On
a historical inaccuracy by Acemoglu and Robinson
Luis
Guillermo Vélez Álvarez
Economist
When I read the celebrated
book of Acemoglu and Robinson six years ago, the part devoted to Colombia seemed superficial, with some inaccuracies and
marked by a certain ideological bias. I wondered if something similar would
happen to readers in other countries whose development processes are referred
to by the authors. I left this in the review I then made of the book, published
in this blog[1].
My
attention was also drawn to the statement that in their eagerness to maintain
the extractive institutions that benefited them, the elites of some countries
blocked industrialization and the introduction of new technologies that could
threaten their survival.
The following is read:
“In
Russia and Austria-Hungary, it wasn´t simply the neglect and mismanagement of
the elites and insidious economic slide under extractive institutions that
prevented industrialization; instead, the rulers actively blocked any attempt
of introduce these technologies and basic investments in infrastructure such as
railroads that could have acted as their conduits”[2]
And
later:
“Second, he opposed the construction
of railways, one of the key new technologies that came with the Industrial Revolution.
When a plan to build a northern railway was put before Francis, he replied, No,
no, I will have nothing to do with it, lest the revolution might come into the
country”[3]
These
statements did not match what I had read elsewhere.
In
the case of Russia, the history of the armored train in which Lenin and his
friends were transported from Germany to lead the revolution is well known. It
is also known that Trotsky moved freely throughout Russia in an armed train
during the civil war. Anyway, Anna Karenina travels by train between St. Petersburg and Moscow and
commits suicide by throwing herself at the wheels of a moving train.
On the Austro-Hungarian
Empire, I remembered that, in his biography of Böhm-Bawerk, Schumpeter
attributed the merit of having financed, as finance minister, the construction
of railways, canals and ports keeping the budget balanced. I also remembered that there were railroads in Kakania - the country of
Bonadea, Leona and Diotima, the beloved of Ulrich, the man without attributes.
At the time I left things like
this, thinking that if the autocrats of Russians and Austro-Hungarians had
opposed the railroad, as Acemoglu and Robinson claimed, they had not been
especially successful in their purpose.
Recently I found, in the also celebrated
Angus Deaton book, "The Great Escape", a reference to the text of
Acemoglu and Robinson and this statement that brings me back to the matter:
“Similarly,
Francis I, Emperor of Austria, banned railways because of their potential to
bring about revolution and threaten his power”[4]
Let's
see some facts:
Francisco José I ascends to
the throne in 1848 and reigns until 1916. He is emperor during the second half
of the nineteenth century, during which the great expansion of the railroad in
Europe. The world's first railway
line opens in England in 1830, linking the cities of Liverpool and Manchester. In
1837 the Kaiser Ferdinands-Norbahn was founded, the first steam locomotive
company in Austria that extends lines between Vienna and other cities of the Empire.
In 1846 the first line linking the cities of Pest and Vác was inaugurated in
Hungary. Between 1846 and 1868, many lines are developed by private companies.
In this last year, one after the establishment of the dual monarchy, Magyar
Államvasutak - Hungarian State Railways is founded. In 1884 the Royal State
Railways of Imperial Austria were founded, the result of the nationalization of
several private companies, some with foreign capital. At the end of the 19th
century, the Empire had several thousand kilometers of railway lines.
The
Russian railways used by Lenin and Trotsky were not built by the Bolsheviks.
They were there for a long time and, according to historian David Landes, were
built by the Tsarist state itself. In 1917 there were more than 80.000 kilometers of railway in Russia. The extraordinary Trans-Siberian Railway, of more than 9.000 kilometers, was built between 1891 and 1904.
“In
Russia, the state assisted banking and industry, and the railroads were
state-built, owned, and operated. Commerce and topography be damned. The
emblematic example: the construction of the first important line, from Moscow
to St. Petersburg. The tsar was asked to select the route. He took a ruler and
drew a straight line between the two cities. But the tip of one finger
stuckout, so the line was built with one curved section”[5]
Nor
does it seem to be true, as Acemoglu and Robinson claim, that Tsarist autocracy
has wanted to hamper industrialization. At least that is not what Landes says:
“Russia,
poor Russia, was the epitome of state-driven development (…) Russian industrial
product rose 5 to 6 percent a year between 1885 and 1900, and again between
1909 and 1912. Railroad mileage doubled between 1890 and 1904, and iron and
steel output increased ten times from 1880 to 1900. Between 1860 and 1914,
Russia went from the seventh to the fifth largest industrial power in the
world. No small achievement, but long forgotten, because later, after the
revolutions of 1917, Communist spokesmen and their foreign adulators rewrote
history so as to blacken the reputation of the tsarist regime, while throwing
favorable testimonies down the memory hole”.[6]
Finally,
because of the fact that an image is worth a thousand words, the map of
Europe's rail network is shown at the beginning of the 20th century. The
Russian and Austro-Hungarian empires do not look like the deprived railway
lines that would be expected after reactionary autocracies hindered their
development.
Europe's rail network in the early
20th century
The
historical slip of Acemoglu and Robinson - welcomed by Deaton - cannot be
interpreted as a minor mistake because the development theory presented in his
acclaimed book depends to a large extent.
Nations
progress when the virtuous circle of inclusive economic and political
institutions occurs and fail when extractive institutions coincide in economic
and political terms. When the combination of extractive and inclusive
institutions is presented, an unstable equilibrium occurs that should lead to a
revolutionary or authoritarian rupture that leads to the inclusive-inclusive
combination, which leads to progress, or to the extractive-extractive that
leads to backwardness. Without valid historical facts that theory does not go
beyond being a tautology.
For
his part, Deaton falls into error when he argues that the increase in
inequality associated with economic progress can be induced by the action of
those who, having benefited from such progress, those who have managed to make
the Great Escape, “protect their positions by destroying the escape routes that
remain behind them.” That was not the case, at least in the case of the
Austro-Hungarian Empire that uncritically takes from Acemoglu and Robinson to
illustrate his thesis.
LGVA
October
2019.
[2] Acemoglu,
D. and Robinson, J.A. (2012). Why
nations fail. Crown Business, New York, 2012. Page 222.
[3] Acemoglu,
D. and Robinson, J.A. (2012). Why
nations fail. Crown Business, New York, 2012. Page 226.
[4] Deaton,
Angus. The great escape: health, wealth
and the origins of inequality. Princeton University Press. USA, 2013. Page
11.
[5]
Landes, D.S. The Wealth and Poverty of
Nations: why some are so rich and some so poor. W-W Norton & Company.
New York-London. 1998. Page: 265.
[6] Landes,
D.S. The Wealth and Poverty of Nations:
why some are so rich and some so poor. W-W Norton & Company. New
York-London. 1998. Page: 268.
Mhhm aqui hay muchosverrores de edición y es difícil entender el mensaje ( había leido la entrada anterior sobre Acemoglu y estaba de acuerdo con que estaba mal lo que decían sobre Rusia y Austro-Hungría) por ejemplo el título debería decir "by Acemoglu and Robinson".
ResponderEliminar